Wednesday, June 30, 2010

Artificial States and Anarchy

As part of secession week 2010, I have a guest post at Let A Thousand Nations Bloom on artificial states and anarchy related to African development.



Monday, June 28, 2010

World Cup and Economic Freedom

Art Carden has a entertaining post at DOL on how the World Cup would play out if the outcome were based on the country's economic freedom score (Chile wins over England in the finale).

For what it's worth, if I knew nothing about the quality of the teams in the tournament, but was trying to win a bracket pool, my prior would be to rank teams inversely to their economic freedom score. My reasoning? Soccer requires virtually no accumulation of capital. All you need is a field, a ball, and something that can serve as the goal. Contrast that with (American) football, basketball, track (at least the sprints, any sprinter will tell you the importance of surface practice and block work), swimming, etc.

I would add the spreading worldwide popularity of basketball (which is more capital intensive than soccer, but not incredibly so) as evidence to this phenomenon, while admitting it is largely ex-post story telling.

Monday, June 21, 2010

Soccer Thoughts

I was not a soccer fan growing up, but have over the last three World Cup come to appreciate the competition. This World Cup has been very enjoyable thus far. My thoughts:

1. A first-rate (read: English Premier League, La Liga, Serie A or Bundesliga) soccer league would excel in the United States. Don't let anyone tell you otherwise. Americans embrace the highest-quality version of just about anything. Relegation is something they would buy into whole-heartedly.

2. Epstein offers his changes for the soccer here; this isn't the first time, nor the tenth, nor the last time you'll see articles in this vain. You won't see changes in soccer until you see these sentiments in the places where soccer matters, just like you won't see a growing feeling of salary inequity from Argentinians affect large-scale labor change in Major League Baseball. As best as I can tell, the calls for modifying soccer are uniquely American. (Though please comment about other cultures that want to change the game, I'd love to read it.)

3. Given the success of Twenty20, I wonder if the best way of moving forward with modifying soccer isn't to create a new sub-sport in and of itself. There have been other instances of such attempts-- what comes to my mind is Arena football and the XFL, though I'm sure there are others-- but to me, those seemed to be modifications that tried to keep the part of a sport that people liked (fast/big plays) while adding in gimmicks to attempt to differentiate it (indoors, cameras everywhere, no fair catches, no punting, etc.). Twenty20 kept the sport the same but got rid of what people didn't like (the length of a cricket match). Maybe that's splitting hairs, but to me it's an important difference.

4. Given #3, perhaps a modified game that compliments soccer would be successful-- or rather, if action had to be taken, this would have the best chance of succeeding. Like above, keep the game and get rid of what people here don't seem to enjoy. Per Epstein, find a way for more scoring, less importance for referees but keep the games commercial-free by half.

Ultimately, I think compliment instead of substitute is the way to go.

Television Future

The Economist recently had a special report on television; I thought the best pieces were these two, though you can find more of them easily at the Economist's page. They raise an interesting question: Television is looking like it's coming upon some tough times, how will it make it through? But, as the Economist notes, we've heard this story before with television and TV's as strong as ever. I had never really considered the vitality and mutability of television but it's important to note.

On the other end of the spectrum, here's CNN preaching the end of television.

Friday's Radio Spot

Here is my interview with Pittsburgh Business Radio on Friday, by myself this time. I was there for about an hour and we talked about Zappos, the BP oil spill and the highest altitude by which someone survived a free fall to the ground.

Econ 101: John Glenn Edition

John Glenn, veritable American space hero, gives a nice example of the fallacy of considering sunk costs in marginal decision making:

"The cost of continuing [the space] shuttle is really very tiny compared to the $100 billion investment we've made in the station..."


Friday, June 18, 2010

Bank Runs and Deposit Insurance

Why do bank runs take place? Demand deposits are bank liabilities. When a bank suffers a loss, it becomes less able to meet all its obligations. To ensure that they are among the obligations that are met, individuals queue up at the bank demanding deposits be paid out. No one wants to be at the back of the line, as it is possible you get less than the full value of your debt claim. In fact, you might end up with nothing.

There are a handful of ways of preventing bank runs.
1. Suspension of Payments
If banks can suspend payments when a run becomes evident, they will have more time to figure out whether they can successfully meet all obligations. If they are solvent (i.e. can meet its obligations), there is no benefit to being the first in line when the bank opens back up so no run takes place. If it is insolvent, they will have to liquidate assets and pay each customer a fraction of debt claims. There is no need to run in this situation as there is no fear of ending up in the "back of the line."

2. Unlimited Liability Shareholders
If some shareholders have unlimited liability, there is no need to run. Those at the "back of the line" would be compensated by unlimited liability shareholders. So there is no reason to form a line.

3. Federal Deposit Insurance
The reasoning here is the same as #2 above. The difference is that it encourages shareholders to engage in riskier behavior, as they will not have to foot the bill if the bank fails.

4. Make debt claims equity claims.
The reasoning here is similar to that of suspension of payments by an insolvent bank. Rather than holding debt claims, customers have equity claims. And the price of an equity share fluctuates on the open market. So if the value of the claim falls, it does so across all shares simultaneously. Again, there is no "back of the line" so no one runs.

Money market mutual funds--where individuals hold equity claims--should be run-proof. Why then did the US Treasury Department guarantee MMMFs in September 2008?
The temporary guarantee program provides coverage to shareholders for amounts that they held in participating money market funds as of the close of business on September 19, 2008. The guarantee will be triggered if a participating fund's net asset value falls below $0.995, commonly referred to as breaking the buck.

The program is designed to address temporary dislocations in credit markets.
In other words, the government provided deposit insurance--which is typically justified as preventing runs--on run-proof deposits. Does anyone know another reason to insure equity claims?

Wednesday, June 16, 2010

Why You Should Study Economics Before Mountain Climbing

Props to the Slate interviewer (bold) of prominent climbing expert Ed Viesturs (italics), on the biggest mistake of his climbing career:

What kept you from acting on your knowledge that it was a mistake?

You know, I was so torn. Part of me was thinking, "Is this really as bad as I think it is?" Here you've spent two and a half months of your life trying to achieve a goal, and you're within 1,000 feet of getting to the top, and it's one of the worst times to have to make these choices. You think, "Arrrrghhhhh, you know, if I turn around right now, we'll have to go home, we've spent all this time and energy, and we won't have made it to the summit." So that's pulling me in one way, and then the other way is going, "Jeez, Ed, it's going to be terrible, just turn around, just go down."

But you didn't.

No. I kept saying, "Well, let me go on for another 15 minutes and then I'll decide." And then after 15 minutes I'd say, "Let me go on another 15 minutes and then I'll decide." And I just couldn't make a decision, and I put it off so long that I got to the top.

Economists call that sunk costswhen you've poured so much money or effort into something that it's hard to extricate yourself, even when you should.

Right! I can see that. In fact, I've seen it many times. And I'd always thought, it doesn't matter how long you've been there, how much money you've spent, how much energy you've expended. If the situation isn't good, go down. The mountain's always going to be there. You can always go back.

Tuesday, June 15, 2010

Blockquoting X

X = Laurence J. Kotlikoff, from his new book Jimmy Stewart is Dead:
Is the U.S. Bankrupt? Bankruptcy is always in the eyes of the creditor. And there are clearly people and countries continuing to voluntarily lend the U.S. government money at what appear to be absurdly low rates. But I'm not one of them because my answer to this question is a firm yes. Given the magnitude of our fiscal gap, our country is absolutely and desperately broke. We were broke before the financial crisis hit, and we are now in much worse shape given the vast sums we've spent trying to save Main Street from Wall Street (p. 78).

Notice of Roster Change

Notice at the right of the screen, Emily Schaeffer is now Emily Skarbek.

Congratulations, you two!!!

Monday, June 14, 2010

Property Rights for the Poor: Effects of Land Titling

By Sebastian Galiani and Ernesto Schargrodsky, forthcoming in JPE (ungated):
Secure property rights are considered a key determinant of economic development. The evaluation of the causal effects of property rights, however, is a difficult task as their allocation is typically endogenous. To overcome this identification problem, we exploit a natural experiment in the allocation of land titles. In 1981, squatters occupied a piece of land in a poor suburban area of Buenos Aires. In 1984, a law was passed expropriating the former owners’ land to entitle the occupants. Some original owners accepted the government compensation, while others disputed the compensation payment in the slow Argentine courts. These different decisions by the former owners generated an exogenous allocation of property rights across squatters. Using data from two surveys performed in 2003 and 2007, we find that entitled families substantially increased housing investment, reduced household size, and enhanced the education of their children relative to the control group. These effects, however, did not take place through improvements in access to credit. Our results suggest that land titling can be an important tool for poverty reduction, albeit not through the shortcut of credit access, but through the slow channel of increased physical and human capital investment, which should help to reduce poverty in the future generations.

Thursday, June 10, 2010

Assorted thoughts

1. I noticed this yesterday on ESPN: "NBA gets an 'A' for diversity"

Sounds kinda like Justin's favorite practice-- measuring income inequality! And how do we measure diversity? The underlying idea behind grading diversity comes from The Institute for Diversity and Ethics in Sport's grading scale for all sports (see page 15):

"Grades for race are determined in relation to overall American demographics. Federal affirmative action policies state that a workplace should reflect the percentages of people in different racial groups, as found in the general population. Approximately 24 percent of the U.S. population are people of color; therefore, if 24 percent of an organization’s employees are people of color, the group received an employment grade of “A” for race, and so on..."

If you feel measuring diversity is important, that seems like a decent way of doing so. I suppose perfect diversity would be equal percentages of all groups, but normalizing it the underlying demographics seems reasonable. But here's their comment on the NBA's player pool (see page 4):

"In the NBA, 82 percent of the players were people of color, the same as last year, tied for the highest percentage of players of color since the 1994‐95 season. The percentage of African‐American players remained at 77 percent since last year’s Racial and Gender Report Card. This was the highest percentage of African‐American players since the 2001‐02 season.

In the NBA’s 2009‐10 season, 18 percent were white and three percent were Latino. This was again the lowest percentage of white players since the 1994‐95 season. Asians comprised one percent of NBA rosters, and an additional one percent of players are people of color categorized as “other.” The percentage of Latino players remained the same as the last three seasons (three percent) while the percentage of white players decreased from 20 percent in the 2007‐08 season.

Eighteen percent of the players were international, which was the same as the 2008‐09 season.

NBA Grade for Players:
Race: A+"

So in sum: The goal is to provide the best grades for those leagues that best match the underlying demographics of the United States. 82 percent of the NBA's players are of color; rough estimates put the underlying U.S. percentage at ten to fifteen percent. Eighteen percent of the NBA's players were white; rough estimates put the underlying U.S. percentage at 65 to 75 percent. Asians are one percent of the NBA and roughly 5% of the U.S. population. Latinos are 3% of the NBA and roughly 15% of the U.S. population.

I wonder which part of that produces an A+ grade.

2. I got through most of Numbers Rule: The Vexing Mathematics of Democracy, from Plato to the Present on a couple of flights recently; it's very accessible and would make a great supplement (pick and choose what you like) for an undergraduate Public Economics class. It gets at the difficulties raised by what I believe to be the overarching issue of public economics: We live in societies and thus need to make some decisions as a group. How should we do that?

There's also a great chapter on the political economy of choosing the appropriate system to distribute seats in the House of Representatives.

Thursday, June 03, 2010

Juicing the Mitchell: Almost Perfect Games Edition

If you're a baseball fan, chances are you've heard about yesterday's Detroit/Cleveland game. Here's the game's recap; additional commentary is not lacking if you so desire it. While I personally don't think it's terribly hard to understand why he called him safe (while the batter was out, there were three things for the umpire to look at during a closer-than-commentators-want-to-admit play), and moreover, it would be a horrible idea to reverse the call (no logically sound reason would exist for not changing any future play once the precedent of changing outcomes is set), that's not the point of this post.

Longtime TPS stalwart Rob Holub points us to yet another legislative Pareto-improvement-- making sure things like this don't ever happen again! (Emphasis is mine.)

"Michigan Gov. Jennifer Granholm, a Democrat, issued the proclamation and said on a radio interview that Mr. Galarraga "was robbed." Meanwhile, Michigan Sen. Debbie Stabenow, also a Democrat, urged Mr. Selig to invoke the "Best Interests of the Game" clause to declare Mr. Galarraga's performance perfect, and Democratic Rep. John Dingell says he'd introduce a congressional resolution asking MLB to overturn the call."

Will, when it comes time to enter the academic job market, there better be a mention of you being the father of "Juicing the Mitchell" somewhere in your job application packet.